Some the most important and beneficial achievements of the Trump administration have occurred at the crossroads of antitrust and intellectual property.
A recent Heritage Foundation report sums up the consumer welfare standard as antitrust law’s being “concerned solely with economic welfare (as opposed to an approach that included vague noneconomic objectives) and it should help to ensure that consumers were protected from anticompetitive behavior.”
The consumer welfare standard, because of its well-reasoned, well-founded basis, has delivered an objective measure and impartial approach to matters of monopolization — the power to control prices or exclude competitors coupled with exclusionary conduct.
Mr. Delrahim observes that “the consumer welfare standard has served as a neutral principle for the administration of the antitrust laws. It focuses enforcers and courts on harm to competition and requires them to evaluate competitive effects. The consumer welfare standard is agnostic to considerations other than the actual competitive process.”
The D.C. Circuit decided U.S. v. Microsoft (2001) on the consumer welfare standard: “[T]o be condemned as exclusionary, a monopolist’s act must have an ‘anticompetitive effect.’ That is, it must harm the competitive process and thereby harm consumers. In contrast, harm to one or more competitors will not suffice.” The court found several of Microsoft’s practices were exclusionary without sufficient efficiency benefits.
Alden Abbott, FTC general counsel and former Heritage scholar, clarifies the Sherman Act’s Section 2 monopolization: “Most successful early government enforcement actions were against hardcore cartels and mergers to monopoly — cases that would not raise an eyebrow today. Indeed, the two major cases involving structural break-ups of dominant enterprises — Standard Oil and American Tobacco — involved predatory practices and mergers to monopoly that clearly would be attacked by current antitrust enforcers.”
The Supreme Court unanimously has applied the consumer welfare standard in judging individual corporate conduct. It ruled in Verizon v. Trinko (2004): “The mere possession of monopoly power, and the concomitant charging of monopoly prices, is not only not unlawful; it is an important element of the free-market system. The opportunity to charge monopoly prices — at least for a short period — is what attracts ‘business acumen’ in the first place; it induces risk taking that produces innovation and economic growth. To safeguard the incentive to innovate, the possession of monopoly power will not be found unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct.
“Firms may acquire monopoly power by establishing an infrastructure that renders them uniquely suited to serve their customers. . . . [A]s a general matter, the Sherman Act ‘does not restrict the long recognized right of [a] trader or manufacturer engaged in an entirely private business, freely to exercise his own independent discretion as to parties with whom he will deal.’” Trinko recognizes innovation effects while denying a duty to deal to help one’s competitors.
To be sure, there are bad actors and bad acts that breach antitrust laws. Some firms holding monopoly power don’t break antitrust law under the consumer welfare standard’s tests. They haven’t acted anticompetitively. Yet, as DOJ has shown, other laws often provide remedies that appropriately apply.
For example, Google and Amazon practice predatory infringement of patents and IP. Restoration of strong IP rights, improving access to injunctive relief and treble damages against willful infringers, would bolster the ability of innovators to hold behemoths accountable. Section 230 reform or repeal could make Internet platforms accountable to police IP-infringing content and not only take it down one instance at a time, but make sure it stays offline. Antitrust scrutiny of mergers or acquisitions where monopolists aim to gobble up potential competitors to quash competition rather than enhance the big company’s efficiency is in order.
Conservatives and those who revere private property rights and the Rule of Law should pay close attention to what should be conserved. Throwing a bedrock legal standard that ensures fairness and objectivity in antitrust — and thus promotes free enterprise, dynamic competition and property rights — overboard for a short-term, specific target would be radical, destructive, and unprincipled.